Which of the following was true of the typical eighteenth-century family in western europe?

Try the new Google Books

Check out the new look and enjoy easier access to your favorite features

Which of the following was true of the typical eighteenth-century family in western europe?


Page 2

Between the late nineteenth century and the 1960s, social theorists argued that economic development was inversely associated with complex family forms. The idea originated with Frédéric Le Play, one of the earliest scholars to undertake empirical analysis of the family. Le Play idealized stem families, in which one child remained at home to work on the family farm and eventually inherit it, thus continuing the family line. In 1872, Le Play wrote that stem families were disappearing “among the working class populations subject to the new manufacturing system of Western Europe” (Silver 1982: 260). Durkheim (1888) expanded on Le Play’s interpretation, stressing the loss of specialized functions of the family and weakening of kin ties with the growth of social differentiation (Lamanna 2002: 61). Burgess (1916) generalized the theory that the nuclear family emerged as a consequence of industrialization, and by the middle of the twentieth century the idea that simple nuclear families were functionally adapted to industrial society became a fundamental tenet of sociological thought (Ogburn 1933; Parsons 1944). Goode (1963: 6), reflecting this consensus, wrote that “wherever the economic system expands through industrialization … extended kinship ties weaken, lineage patterns dissolve, and a trend toward some form of the conjugal system generally begins to appear.”

Policy analysts discussing changes in the living arrangements of the aged in the first half of the twentieth century similarly emphasized the declining importance of agriculture and the rise of industrial wage labor. The creators of the Social Security system—the landmark US old-age support program, adopted in 1936—routinely justified the need for assistance in terms of the decline of farming and the flight of the younger generation to cities (Eliot 1961; Clague 1961; Brown 1969; Helvering v Davis 301 U.S. 619 [1937]). Mid-twentieth-century literature on aging frequently raised the same points about agriculture and urbanization to explain the increasing tendency for the elderly to reside alone (e.g., Burgess 1960; Cowgill 1974; Nimkoff 1962).

A revisionist paradigm emerged in the 1960s. Laslett and Harrison (1963) discovered that only a tenth of households in the village of Clayworth in the seventeenth century included extended kin—a fraction almost identical to that reported by the 1961 census of England and Wales. Laslett and his colleagues soon demonstrated that Clayworth was not an anomaly; there was similar evidence for many other preindustrial English and Northwest European villages (Laslett 1965, 1972). Over the next two decades, Laslett and his followers elaborated a theory that Northwest Europe had, from a very early date, a unique family system characterized by nuclear family structure and neolocal marriage (Hajnal 1982; Laslett 1983; Reher 1998). Almost immediately after Laslett’s first publications on the family, historians asserted that nuclear families had also been standard in England’s North American colonies from the time of earliest settlement (Demos 1965; Greven 1966). American social historians were soon among the most prominent and enthusiastic supporters of the hypothesis that the nuclear family had predominated for centuries in both North America and Northwest Europe (e.g., Hareven 1994, 1996).

Proponents of the nuclear family hypothesis argue that that in Northwest Europe and North America—especially England and its colonies—adult children ordinarily left their parental home and established new households when they married. Many scholars maintain that elderly persons resided with their children only in cases of poverty or infirmity, circumstances that could force aged parents to move into their children’s household (Hareven 1994, 1996; Kertzer 1995; Hammel 1995; Smith 1979). Advocates of the hypothesis further maintain that these “weak-family” patterns were unique to Northwest Europe and North America, and that the rest of the world had “strong-family” systems with much higher levels of intergenerational coresidence (Reher 1998; Hartman 2004; Hajnal 1982). This idea of a unique Northwest European family system has been seen by some as an essential stimulus for the early development of capitalism and industrialization (Macfarlane 1978, 1986, 1987; Cain and McNicoll 1988; Hartman 2004). Despite extensive criticism of the methods and measurements used by Laslett and his followers (e.g., Berkner 1972, 1975; Ruggles 1987, 1994, 2003), the hypothesis that Northwest European and North American families were exceptional in their preference for nuclear residence remains the dominant interpretation (Hartman 2004; Thornton 2005).

In the literature dealing with the rest of the world, there is some empirical support for the thesis that economic development is associated with a decline in family complexity. There is clear evidence, for example, of diminished intergenerational coresidence in Japan, Korea, and Taiwan, which have experienced rapid economic growth and development (Martin 1990; Hirosima 1997; Hermalin, Ofstedal, and Chang 1992; De Vos and Lee 1993; Knodel and Debavalya 1997; Chattopadhyay and Marsh 1999). Bongaarts and Zimmer (2002) found a country-level cross-sectional relationship between schooling and nuclear family structure, suggesting that as educational levels increase, residential family complexity declines. Some comparative survey data also suggest a trend toward independent residence of the aged in developing countries (United Nations 2005). Other recent studies, however, suggest that there have been no clear trends in coresidence in less-developed countries (Logan and Bian 1999; Bongaarts 2001; Palloni 2001; Knodel and Ofstedal 2002; Ruggles and Heggeness 2008).

This article evaluates the case for European and North American exceptionalism in nuclear family residence by exploiting a vast collection of newly available historical and contemporary data from 87 censuses of 34 countries around the world between 1850 and 2007. My goal is to begin to systematically assess cross-temporal and cross-national variation in the living arrangements of persons aged 65 or older.

The family patterns of the aged are a key indicator for the European exceptionalism hypothesis. All things being equal, one would expect that populations with weak nuclear family systems and neolocal marriage would have comparatively low residence of aged persons with kin or in multigenerational families. By contrast, elderly in strong-family societies in which stem families or joint families predominate would be expected to have relatively high coresidence. Accordingly, I compare living arrangements of the aged in nineteenth-century Northwest Europe and North America to the living arrangements of the aged in both developed and developing countries in the second half of the twentieth century, applying a basic set of controls for agricultural employment and demographic conditions.1

The results suggest that nineteenth-century Northwest Europe and North America did not have exceptionally simple or nuclear family structure. In fact, the family patterns in the historical data from these countries are generally similar to the family patterns found in the recent past in countries that share similar levels of agricultural employment and demographic characteristics.

This study is based on census microdata from three sources. The North Atlantic Population Project (NAPP 2006) provided data from six censuses taken between 1865 and 1901 in Canada, England and Wales, Norway, Scotland, and Sweden. The Integrated Public Use Microdata Series—referred to below as IPUMS-USA—provided data from the US decennial censuses of 1880 through 2000, and from the American Community Survey of 2007 (Ruggles et al. 2008). The International Integrated Public Use Microdata Series—known as IPUMS-International—provided data from 65 censuses of 28 countries dating from the period 1960 through 2002 (Minnesota Population Center 2007).

All censuses available from these three databases in December 2008 were included in the analysis except for those with inadequate information on family interrelationships or agricultural employment.2 For the IPUMS-USA censuses, I relied on the one percent samples available for each census year. In the case of the NAPP and IPUMS-International databases, I used an online sampling tool available on the project websites to draw 200,000 households from each census, except for a few censuses for which fewer than 200,000 households are available. The Appendix Table provides the basic characteristics of each sample.

Characteristics of census samples of elderly (65+) populations and values of variables used in the analysis

Enumer-ation

rule

Sample sizePercent of elderly
residing with
Agri-culturalemploy-

mentb

Percent
elderlyc
Maritalfertility

ratiod

Un-marriedelderly

womene

Marriedelderly

couplesf

Marriage age
TotalElderlyaAny
kin
Descen-
dants
Threegener-

ations

FemalegMaleh
Nineteenth-century censuses
Canada 1901De facto264,68611,11273.664.224.937.75.187.434.844.525.528.5
England/Wales 1881De facto956,80637,56059.147.121.912.64.688.742.137.524.825.7
Norway 1875De jure625,46129,82956.555.921.441.16.087.641.634.527.328.5
Norway 1900De jure966,40361,99648.043.511.636.47.899.740.239.026.728.0
Scotland 1881De facto954,58541,44265.453.325.214.05.0100.550.528.725.427.4
Sweden 1900De facto726,91150,81241.839.710.535.68.399.242.136.327.529.6
United States 1880De jure502,81914,93771.664.231.343.03.586.139.142.723.226.9
United States 1900De jure760,08127,19368.761.327.834.64.174.639.139.223.727.5
East Asia
Cambodia 1998De facto1,021,20830,80788.463.641.661.83.576.050.835.222.524.2
China 1982De facto824,33235,23775.070.252.064.54.948.946.631.222.325.0
China 1990De jure751,23334,68775.170.954.861.85.546.543.635.822.123.8
Malaysia 1980De facto182,6016,32777.169.949.927.13.877.543.337.223.926.9
Malaysia 1991De facto347,89211,54978.872.749.621.53.874.145.839.624.628.0
Malaysia 2000De facto435,30014,48278.573.245.515.03.968.243.943.424.928.5
Philippines 1990De facto1,040,99629,57182.464.938.135.53.485.340.445.723.726.1
Philippines 1995De jure1,006,52528,94481.867.636.736.53.582.240.645.124.126.6
Philippines 2000De jure982,34131,70380.165.135.532.83.874.940.844.023.926.5
Vietnam 1989De facto982,68336,72980.877.454.857.24.877.451.036.223.224.1
Latin America
Argentina 1970De facto466,89228,19864.851.124.815.37.060.745.235.323.026.3
Argentina 1980De facto793,38447,45060.547.125.012.48.167.146.436.622.825.4
Argentina 1991De facto747,08953,84953.742.420.44.18.863.247.637.123.225.8
Brazil 1960De jure979,39023,67876.566.334.052.42.899.142.041.622.426.0
Brazil 1991De jure845,93533,84269.461.431.322.84.859.343.843.622.825.8
Brazil 2000De jure763,87835,84867.959.429.516.35.847.944.342.423.026.4
Chile 1970De jure890,48140,19574.353.431.422.55.179.446.332.823.325.6
Chile 1982De facto803,30940,67471.756.434.018.35.855.745.935.323.625.7
Chile 1992De facto713,17040,18169.755.733.816.56.653.546.335.523.425.7
Chile 2002De facto622,82641,80465.152.929.311.88.140.344.837.124.327.5
Colombia 1973De jure1,138,74032,36980.765.040.032.93.187.146.232.922.326.1
Colombia 1993De facto831,41733,16680.465.738.621.34.553.343.936.822.626.0
Colombia 2005De facto781,30245,58074.662.635.99.76.250.243.836.823.026.4
Costa Rica 1984De jure241,2209,07575.162.334.831.54.568.040.540.122.125.2
Costa Rica 2000De jure381,50017,82668.658.829.319.45.651.140.839.822.126.0
Ecuador 1974De jure648,67820,31376.264.841.345.73.899.343.037.221.324.9
Ecuador 1982De facto806,83427,48974.162.938.431.44.086.140.539.821.424.8
Ecuador 1990De facto791,47529,08272.861.936.029.84.468.140.141.522.025.0
Ecuador 2001De facto685,89339,03375.748.526.525.66.653.340.533.821.324.6
Mexico 1990De jure984,18634,79470.861.532.421.34.265.240.743.822.424.6
Mexico 2000De jure874,76538,02073.364.435.916.35.056.541.142.622.825.0
Panama 1970De jure150,4735,04271.660.838.343.03.792.143.630.820.724.9
Panama 1980De facto195,5777,57472.660.037.325.74.368.941.134.321.525.0
Panama 1990De facto232,73710,75871.559.837.727.95.358.939.435.922.025.4
Panama 2000De facto284,08114,54570.960.637.221.46.057.040.835.322.025.8
Venezuela 1981De facto891,16728,38179.460.438.011.93.577.747.030.621.224.9
Venezuela 1990De jure768,47428,57680.661.437.413.04.065.346.931.722.125.2
Venezuela 2001De jure714,92430,75980.367.740.39.94.950.845.633.722.826.1
Sub-Saharan Africa
Ghana 2000De jure951,78947,45289.353.932.642.75.359.944.225.422.527.1
Rwanda 2002De facto843,39221,17176.473.350.358.42.9102.049.137.823.926.5
South Africa 1996De jure728,65931,70372.959.742.55.44.845.254.131.027.330.0
South Africa 2001De facto752,40034,27076.267.652.05.55.044.456.829.728.130.9
Middle East
Iraq 1997De facto1,464,19442,15193.883.357.513.93.4116.946.644.523.927.1
Israel 1972De jure315,60818,75838.934.314.714.57.177.539.347.622.725.4
Israel 1983De jure403,47428,80023.621.06.64.78.967.640.646.824.326.3
Israel 1995De jure556,36543,58326.324.210.22.39.965.344.542.524.327.3
Palestine 1997De facto259,1917,40881.473.642.38.13.4121.145.247.021.025.3
Eastern/SE Europe
Belarus 1999De jure513,43556,23932.628.712.74.213.530.556.134.722.825.2
Greece 1971De facto678,17462,95967.959.334.927.711.257.244.143.323.528.0
Greece 1981De facto627,46565,33954.747.325.820.913.150.741.846.722.627.4
Greece 1991De facto594,05066,99148.541.118.615.014.239.441.847.224.729.4
Greece 2001De facto559,52273,72643.837.912.910.517.237.839.050.326.731.1
Hungary 1980De facto507,05956,44143.633.915.65.913.541.449.237.720.924.7
Hungary 1990De facto472,42152,18137.429.011.94.413.236.352.634.722.325.8
Romania 1992De jure614,61054,99339.235.119.915.611.141.845.542.921.925.4
Romania 2002De jure584,53065,34942.036.019.418.314.231.745.443.023.827.2
Western Europe
Austria 1981De facto533,31467,76728.825.112.16.515.238.255.732.923.026.5
Austria 1991De jure503,56861,89428.224.810.74.614.936.655.333.725.027.9
Austria 2001De jure470,94458,28225.522.78.13.115.537.850.737.326.429.4
France 1982De jure543,01858,23124.519.26.36.913.341.050.136.522.624.6
France 1990De jure496,44455,19320.216.64.34.814.041.348.139.524.326.4
Portugal 1981De jure492,28944,93947.527.011.915.211.450.545.441.622.224.6
Portugal 1991De jure459,22849,33442.834.516.812.213.837.143.944.123.926.7
Portugal 2001De jure399,78450,10338.131.913.55.716.536.442.245.925.628.3
Spain 1991De facto652,09668,29652.941.717.112.113.539.044.343.625.928.2
Twentieth-century United States
1910De jure923,15334,21168.560.426.029.74.368.239.938.423.126.9
1920De jure1,050,63442,75365.156.523.525.94.762.338.937.822.526.0
1930De jure1,216,33756,15661.451.821.822.05.452.539.437.122.425.6
1940De jure1,351,73277,09357.347.319.017.66.843.640.636.322.725.5
1950De jure1,922,19888,74748.438.415.212.18.154.941.936.420.723.7
1960De jure1,799,888133,40239.929.211.17.48.968.443.238.820.323.3
1970De jure2,030,386167,46730.522.07.64.610.049.546.437.321.423.5
1980De jure2,267,320206,35424.618.16.13.611.240.047.938.623.325.2
1990De jure2,479,020251,99322.717.76.13.412.843.447.738.525.327.5
2000De jure2,808,457279,25023.119.57.22.912.645.346.837.626.127.9
2007De jure2,994,662351,10424.120.37.83.012.548.145.138.127.429.1

Even though the data span great distances of time and space, they provide closely comparable information on living arrangements. Both nineteenth-century and more recent censuses have generally defined households on the basis of shared meals or a shared physical structure. Family compounds in Africa composed of multiple physical dwellings are ordinarily counted as single households, as long as the residents have a single household head and either eat together or share common housekeeping. One key variation among censuses is in the enumeration rule: some censuses enumerated all persons present in the household on a designated census night (de facto rule), and others enumerated all persons who usually resided in the household (de jure rule). The enumeration rule proved to have significant implications for the measurement of intergenerational coresidence, as described below.3

Household-level measures of family structure—such as those used by Laslett and his followers—are highly sensitive to demographic conditions and therefore inappropriate for comparative analysis of populations with substantially differing demographic behavior. Populations characterized by high fertility and mortality have relatively few elderly persons, and therefore only a small percentage of households have the potential to include elderly kin (Ruggles 2003). In societies that also have late marriage and long generations—such as those of historic Northwest Europe—the potential for multigenerational households is especially limited. In many such populations, the average grandchild was born when the grandparents were in their mid-60s, and people were likely to die before their grandchildren were born or shortly thereafter. Thus, the potential for multigenerational households in preindustrial Northwest Europe was sharply constrained (Ruggles 1987, 1994, 2003).

If we measure coresidence from the perspective of the aged, we minimize the effects of variation in demographic conditions on indicators of family structure. Even in populations where few households have the potential to include elderly kin, the great majority of elderly persons have the demographic potential to reside with offspring. Nevertheless, demographic conditions can affect the living arrangements of elderly people. For example, fertility affects the number of options the elderly have for residing with their children, and marriage age affects the duration of overlap across multiple generations. Accordingly, although measurement from the perspective of the oldest generation greatly reduces the effects of demographic conditions on the potential for intergenerational coresidence, it is important when comparing populations with pronounced differences in demographic conditions to take these differences into account.

This analysis uses three measures of living arrangements of the aged, which are described in Table 1. The elderly population is defined as persons aged 65 or older.4 Married couples in which both partners are aged 65 or older are treated as single observations, since the partners share a single living arrangement.

Measures of living arrangements of individuals and couples aged 65 or older

Percent residing with
Any kinDescendantsThree generations
Nineteenth century
 Britain62.350.223.5
 Nordic countries48.746.414.5
 North America71.363.328.0
Twentieth and twenty-first centuries
 Latin America72.259.133.9
 Middle East52.847.326.2
 Sub-Saharan Africa78.166.946.5
 East Asia79.869.645.9
 Northwest Europe34.327.111.2
 Eastern/Southeastern Europe45.538.719.1
 United States42.334.613.8
Overall mean60.350.527.6
Standard deviation18.416.77.6
Number of census samples848484

This measure assesses the percentage of elderly individuals and couples residing with any kin other than a spouse, including lateral kin such as siblings. The measure has the advantage that it can be consistently applied to virtually any census with a question on the relationship of each individual to a household head or reference person, even when little detail is available. Because of its simplicity, this measure poses the lowest risk of measurement error.

The second measure focuses on residence with descendants, defined as children, children-in-law, or grandchildren of the elderly person or couple. This is intended as a broad indicator of intergenerational coresidence, and may capture temporary residence with children—including unmarried “boomerang” children—as well as the enduring multigenerational families described by Le Play.

The final measure is the percentage of elderly individuals and couples residing with both a child (or child-in-law) and a grandchild. Residence with three generations provides the clearest measure of the multigenerational extended families of the sort envisioned by nineteenth- and twentieth-century social theorists, while circumventing the major problems associated with household-level measures of multigenerational families.5

As shown in Table 1, the level of the three indicators differs substantially: on average, across all samples, over 60 percent of the aged resided with kin, but just 28 percent resided with three generations. Nevertheless, the regional and chronological patterns are broadly similar across the three measures. The lowest coresidence is found in twentieth-century Northwest Europe and the United States, and the highest in sub-Saharan Africa and East Asia. The nineteenth-century samples from Great Britain, the Nordic countries, and North America fall between these extremes.

Figures 1 through 3 show the three family measures for each census sample. The NAPP datasets for nineteenth-century Britain, Norway, Sweden, and Canada are represented by squares, and the IPUMS-USA samples are represented by light green circles. IPUMS-International data from Latin America, Africa, and Asia appear as triangles, and the post-1960 censuses from Europe appear as darker circles.

In all three graphs, the countries fall into distinct clusters. The countries of Africa, Asia, and Latin America have had high coresidence, with the sole exception of Israel, represented by light red triangles. The European samples taken during the past 50 years have much lower coresidence, with the exception of the earliest samples available for Greece. The nineteenth-century data from the United States and Canada generally fall in the same range as the twentieth-century data from developing countries in Africa, Asia, and Latin America, but the nineteenth-century data from Britain and the Nordic region suggest significantly lower coresidence. The United States is the only country with a continuous series of data spanning the entire period, and by all measures it shows dramatic declines in coresidence. For example, Figure 1 shows that 72 percent of elderly in the United States resided with any kin in 1880, and such coresidence dropped to a low point of 23 percent in 1990.

To evaluate whether the data provide evidence for a distinctive Northwest European family pattern, I assess how the data on family structure in the nineteenth-century census samples compare with more recent data on family structure from populations with similar economic and demographic characteristics. The variables used to control for these characteristics are summarized in Table 2.

Independent variables included in the analysis

VariableDefined asMeanStandard deviation
Agricultural employmentNatural log of percent of men aged 18–64 employed in agriculture2.70.9
Percent elderlyPercent of population aged 65 or older7.54.0
Marital fertilityAge-standardized marital fertility ratio62.721.0
Unmarried elderly womenPercent of population 65+ who are women without spouses44.64.4
Married elderly couplesPercent of population 65+ who are residing with spouse38.55.0
De jure censusDe jure census enumeration rule0.60.5

Agricultural employment is of key theoretical importance. The declining role of agriculture in the economy was central to the arguments made by Le Play and early-twentieth-century social theorists about the simplification of family structure. In a recent article (Ruggles 2007), I argued that the decline of agricultural employment among the younger generation was the key determinant of the long-run decline in intergenerational coresidence in the United States. Not only did the traditional family forms depend on agricultural inheritance, but the rise of nonagricultural wage-labor opportunities also provided the incentives for the younger generation to leave the farm. Agricultural employment is one of the few measures of economic development that are closely comparable across virtually every census sample. Agricultural employment is measured here as the natural log of the percentage of men aged 18 to 64 engaged in agricultural work, including farm owners, tenant farmers, and agricultural laborers. The log transformation is needed to accommodate a curvilinear relationship between agricultural employment and the three measures of family composition.

Percent elderly is a powerful variable that summarizes key elements of the prevailing demographic regime. In any population, the percentage of persons aged 65 or older is determined mainly by past fertility and mortality. There are two reasons to expect that percent elderly would be related to coresidence of the elderly. The first is related to the availability of kin. When the percentage of elderly in the population is low, the elderly generally have many younger kin available for coresidence. The second reason pertains to social norms. Some demographers have proposed an indirect effect of the relative size of the elderly population on coresidence, by arguing that growth in the percentage of elderly in the population may undermine the norm of intergenerational coresidence (Levy 1965: 49; Kobrin 1976: 136; cf. Burch 1967; Ruggles 1987). In either case, we would expect an inverse relationship between percent elderly and coresidence.

Marital fertility is intended to control for variation in the opportunity to reside with children. In low-fertility populations, the aged have fewer children with whom they can reside, and some demographers have suggested that this helps explain the low levels of intergenerational coresidence in economically advanced countries (Kobrin 1976; Soldo 1981; Wister and Burch 1983). There is some evidence, however, that this fertility effect is relatively small. In populations where coresidence of the aged is the norm, the likelihood of living with a child appears to be relatively insensitive to the number of surviving children (Knodel et al. 2000; Smith 1986; Ruggles 1994; see also Elman and Uhlenberg 1995).6 Fertility is calculated here as the mean number of own-children under age five per 100 married women aged 15 to 49. I used direct standardization to control for age structure; the standard population was the average across all census samples of the age distribution of married women (Siegel, Swanson, and Shryock 2004: 389–390). It should be noted that this is not a pure measure of marital fertility, since the own-child fertility ratio is also influenced by infant and child mortality.7

I also controlled for the sex and marital status composition of the elderly population. I divided the elderly population into three groups: married couples, unmarried women, and unmarried men. The sex and marital status of the aged population mainly reflects patterns of widowhood and remarriage. It is influenced by mortality levels, differential mortality of men and women, the prevalence of divorce, proportions of men and women remarrying following widowhood or marital disruption, and the proportion of each sex never marrying. In virtually every population, unmarried women are especially likely to reside with kin, and in most populations unmarried men are the group most likely to reside independently. The models explicitly include the percent of elderly persons who are unmarried women and married couples, and unmarried men are the residual category. Overall, an average of 45 percent of the aged were unmarried women, 38 percent were married couples, and the remainder—just 17 percent—were unmarried men.8

Finally, I included an indicator to distinguish between de jure and de facto censuses. The enumeration rules determine whether the census includes persons present on census night (de facto) or persons ordinarily resident in a particular household (de jure). The censuses are split between de jure (56 percent) and de facto (44 percent), and both enumeration rules were used in every period and region under study. This variable did not have a substantial substantive effect on the findings of the analysis, but it did significantly improve the fit of the model.

I use ordinary least squares regression to control for the effects of variation in demographic conditions and agricultural employment on coresidence with kin. My goal is not to assess the statistical significance of each independent variable.9 Demographic and economic conditions are clearly related to family composition, but the primary purpose of the regression exercise is to evaluate the level of coresidence in each census sample. The regressions provide us with a systematic way to assess whether the level of coresidence in a particular country is high or low, given the demographic and economic circumstances. Thus, I use the regression to predict living arrangements of the aged in each census. I then compare the predicted family structure with the actual family structure in each census, to gauge whether a given population has higher or lower elderly coresidence than would be expected on the basis of that population’s economic and demographic characteristics.

Table 3 shows the results of ordinary least squares regressions of agricultural employment and demographic conditions on the measures of living arrangements of the aged. The models fit well, with adjusted R2 of .79 to .84. As expected, the most consistently powerful variables are agricultural employment and percent elderly. Populations with a high percentage of agricultural employment tended to have much higher coresidence of the elderly with kin. As anticipated, the percent elderly was inversely related to coresidence.

OLS regressions of agricultural employment and demographic characteristics on living arrangements of the aged

With any kinWith descendantsThree generations
BStandard errorBStandard errorBStandard error
Agricultural employment8.371.46***8.061.30***6.541.19***
Percent elderly−4.100.37***−3.610.33***−3.110.30***
Marital fertility−0.200.06**−0.150.05**−0.190.05***
Unmarried elderly women0.760.28**1.040.25***1.520.23***
Married elderly couples0.720.24**1.060.21***0.940.19***
De jure census−9.151.83***−5.541.62**−5.481.49***
Constant24.5920.34−19.4518.04−55.9416.60**
Adjusted R square0.840.840.79
N848484

The other four variables were all associated with living arrangements, but not always in the expected way. As anticipated, there is a substantial positive bivariate correlation between fertility and coresidence, perhaps because elderly persons with many children have greater opportunities to coreside. When the percent elderly is controlled, however, the relationship between fertility and coresidence is inverted. This suggests that—controlling for other aspects of the demographic regime—populations with widespread fertility limitation may actually have closer ties between parents and children. The de jure enumeration rule is inversely associated with coresidence, suggesting that the presence of visiting relatives may account for some intergenerational living arrangements.

Figures 4 through 6 plot the predicted percent of aged in each living arrangement based on the equations for each model against the observed percent. In all three graphs, most countries cluster closely around the diagonal line, underscoring the finding that a few simple economic and demographic indicators effectively predict most variation in coresidence. If historical Northwest European and North American families were truly exceptional, we would expect that the observed percentage residing with kin would be lower than the percent predicted by the regression equation—that is, those countries should fall significantly above the diagonal.

Figure 4 shows the observed and predicted coresidence of the elderly with any kin. One of the data points for nineteenth-century Britain (represented by dark squares) is just below the diagonal, and the other is above. The three nineteenth-century Nordic data points (gray squares) are slightly above the line, and nineteenth-century Canada (light yellow square) is slightly below the line. The symbols for the United States (light green circles) are on or above the line. In no case is one of the samples from nineteenth-century Northwest Europe or North America an outlier: the observed coresidence tends to fall within a few percentage points of the predicted coresidence.

The story is similar for Figure 5, which focuses on coresidence with descendant kin. Here, the historical Northwest European countries are all adjacent to the diagonal or fall below it, with the exception of the sample for England and Wales, which is just above the line. There is somewhat more evidence for the hypothesized pattern of historical European exceptionalism in Figure 6, which focuses on three generations; in this analysis, almost all the Northwest European and North American samples fall slightly above the diagonal, suggesting that these countries did have less coresidence than predicted. 10 From a larger perspective, however, even this effect appears fairly trivial. The historical samples in Figure 6 are not outliers: multiple samples from Latin America, Europe, the Middle East, and Asia are farther above the diagonal than any of the historical Northwest European or North American samples. Thus, there is no evidence here for an exceptional weak Northwest European family pattern.

Goody (1996: 17) argued that the sharp distinction drawn by Hajnal (1982) and others between the Northwest European family and living arrangements in the rest of the world “overstresses the actual differences,” and “the data do not altogether justify such a sharp dichotomy.” The evidence presented here reinforces Goody’s interpretation. The living arrangements of the aged in nineteenth-century England and Wales, Scotland, Norway and Sweden, and also in Canada and the United States were similar to those of developing countries in the second half of the twentieth century that had a similar demographic profile and similar levels of employment in agriculture.

This analysis may have implications that go beyond the debate over the Northwest European family pattern. A few basic demographic indicators, together with the percentage of agricultural employment, proved sufficient to predict most variation in living arrangements of the aged over an extraordinarily diverse collection of countries. This suggests that the effects of cultural factors on family structure may not be as great as some scholars have assumed.

I am not arguing, however, that European families were typical in all respects. My purpose is limited to testing the hypothesis that Northwest Europe and North America had an exceptional preference for nuclear family structure. Analysts such as Hajnal (1982) and Hartman (2004) place at least as much emphasis on the distinctive Northwest European patterns of late marriage and a high proportion remaining unmarried as they do on nuclear family structure. As shown in the Appendix Table, Norwegians, Swedes, Scots, and Canadians did have unusually late marriage in the nineteenth century, and these data therefore support that aspect of Northwest European distinctiveness.11

Most of the revisionist literature inspired by Laslett (1965, 1972), however, has focused on family structure rather than marriage age. The new census samples provide nationally representative, high-precision statistics that can for the first time place the living arrangements of nineteenth-century Northwest Europe and North America in broad comparative historical perspective. The results of this comparison demand that we carefully consider the prevailing ideas about the Northwest European family. Accordingly, the paragraphs that follow explore ways we might reconcile the new findings with the theory of Northwest European exceptionalism.

Some might argue that the cross-sectional measures used here are too crude to detect the exceptional character of the Northwest European family. In particular, perhaps Northwest Europe and North America really did have a unique system of neolocal marriage, but also had a unique system of “nuclear reincorporation” under which large numbers of the elderly moved into their children’s homes when they became unable to care for themselves (Kertzer 1995). Under this scenario, even though the living arrangements of the elderly in nineteenth-century Northwest Europe and North America appear similar to those in other parts of the world, they would still be distinctive because they were formed when dependent parents moved in with their children, rather than by children remaining in their parental home. The nuclear reincorporation hypothesis, however, is unlikely to account for the findings presented here. I have presented evidence elsewhere contradicting the hypothesis in the United States (Ruggles 2003, 2007). Moreover, in nineteenth-century Canada, England, Norway, Scotland, and Sweden—as in the United States and most other countries—most intergenerational families were headed by the older generation.12 This makes the nuclear reincorporation hypothesis strained at best. If most intergenerational families were formed through reincorporation, we would have to assume that when frail and impoverished dependent elders moved in with their children for support, they nevertheless assumed headship of the household.

An alternative defense of the idea of the Northwest European nuclear family system could focus on the temporal and geographic limitations of the data analyzed here. This analysis compared data from nineteenth-century Northwest Europe and North America with late-twentieth-century data from around the world. We presently have no comparable census samples from non-Western countries before the mid-twentieth century. Perhaps the less-developed countries of the world at some point in the distant past had strong-family systems, but by the second half of the twentieth century these had already weakened to the point that they appear similar to the weak-family systems of nineteenth-century Northwest Europe and North America. Such a scenario, however, seems unlikely. The best data we have suggest that there has been little change in coresidence in the least-developed countries during the past several decades (Knodel and Ofstedal 2002; Palloni 2001; Ruggles and Heggeness 2008). Accordingly, any general weakening of the family systems of the developing world probably would have had to occur in the mid-twentieth century or earlier, and this seems unlikely.

This analysis also lacks any observations from Northwest Europe before the nineteenth century. Laslett, Hajnal, and others originally identified the Northwest European nuclear family system in data from the seventeenth and eighteenth centuries, whereas the earliest censuses used here date from the nineteenth century. Perhaps Northwest Europe and North America had a weak-family system in the seventeenth and eighteenth centuries, but then developed a strong-family system sometime in the first half of the nineteenth century. Two decades ago I described a “rise of the extended family” in nineteenth-century England and America (Ruggles 1987), and Anderson (1971) argued that industrialization and urbanization in Lancashire brought about an increase in extended living arrangements. My earlier study, however, argued that the apparent increase in the percentage of households with extended kin was actually just an artifact of demographic change: as the proportion of available elderly kin in the population increased, so did the percentage of households containing elderly relatives. I am not aware of any evidence for an increase in coresidence of the aged with kin between the end of the eighteenth century and the mid-nineteenth century. All things considered, the idea that Europe developed a stronger family system after the eighteenth century seems unlikely.13

The simplest interpretation is that the propensity among the aged to reside with kin was not substantially different in preindustrial Northwest Europe and North America than in the rest of the world. As Le Play and the early-twentieth-century theorists suggested, it makes sense in agricultural societies for a child to remain at home after reaching adulthood. Farmers who reached advanced ages needed help with heavy work, and the younger generation hoped to inherit the farm. Growing commercialization and industrialization in Northwest Europe and North America in the nineteenth and twentieth centuries meant that a declining percentage of families had farms. Young people moved to towns, attracted by the high wages and independence offered by jobs in commerce, manufacturing, and transportation. Thus, economic development undermined the material incentives for intergenerational coresidence, and gradually the elderly began to reside separately from their descendants.

I am grateful for the comments and suggestions of George Alter, Catherine Fitch, Joshua Goldstein, Brian Gratton, Alice Kasakoff, Miriam L. King, Hans Jørgen Marker, Mary Louise Nagata, Jan Oldervoll, and Gunnar Thorvaldsen. Several of these colleagues remain unconvinced by my argument, but they all helped me tighten and refine the analysis. Data collection was supported by several grants, most importantly National Institute of Child Health and Human Development grants HD43392, HD044154, HD052110, and HD047283, and National Science Foundation grants SES-0433654, SES-0111707, and SBR-9908380.

Figures in this article are available in color in the electronic edition of the journal.

1It is beyond the scope of this article to summarize the large literature on living arrangements of the aged in developing and developed countries. For recent discussions of these literatures see Bongaarts and Zimmer (2002); Knodel and Ofstedal (2002); Palloni (2001); Ruggles and Heggeness (2008); United Nations (2005). There is also a significant historical literature on living arrangements of the aged; notable contributions include Haber and Gratton (1994); Hareven (1994, 1996); Kertzer (1995); Wall (1989, 1995); Ruggles (1996, 2007).

2Twelve census samples do not provide sufficient information on household relationships to consistently identify the presence of own-children, children-in-law, and grandchildren of the elderly. This problem eliminated all samples for Egypt, Kenya, and Uganda and older samples from Argentina, Costa Rica, France, and the United States. In some cases, the census samples are not organized into households, making it impossible to identify family interrelationships (all recent samples of Canada, Great Britain, and the Netherlands, many Latin American censuses from the 1960s, and Spain in 1981). In several other cases—Norway in 1865, Hungary in 1970, and Mexico in 1970—the relationship variable had excessive missing data; I excluded samples with over 4 percent missing relationship information. Finally, two additional censuses did not allow consistent identification of agricultural employment (Kenya 1999 and Rwanda 1991). In all, I examined 128 samples and excluded 44 owing to data limitations.

3Another potentially important incompatibility is that 13 of the censuses do not include residents of large collective units, such as institutions. In most of the affected countries, however, few elderly resided in such units, and multivariate analysis revealed no significant difference in measures of family composition between the censuses with and without collective households. For a comprehensive discussion of comparability issues, including the official census definitions of household in each census, see Ruggles and Heggeness (2008).

4Age 65 has the advantage, compared with younger thresholds often used for developing countries, that the overwhelming majority of children of the population aged 65 or older are adults, and therefore usually have some choice about where to live. The major liability of the age 65 threshold is that sample surveys often include too few cases for analysis, but that is not a problem with the census microdata samples. Some investigators (e.g., Cowgill and Holmes 1972; Holmes and Holmes 1995; Cattell 1989) have argued that social definitions of old age vary from country to country, but in practice there is no realistic alternative to using a fixed age threshold for the analysis of living arrangements of the aged. In particular, it is inappropriate to measure old age relative to expected years of life remaining. Paradoxically, in populations with early death, the elderly tend to have characteristics that in low-mortality populations are associated with younger age groups. For example, populations with low life expectancy tend to have comparatively high proportions of persons over 65 still in the workforce and with minor children still at home. Accordingly, there is little empirical justification for imposing an earlier threshold for old age in populations that have an earlier age at death.

5As noted above, measures such as Laslett’s extended and multiple family households are greatly affected by prevailing levels of fertility and mortality. Accordingly, these measures are unsuitable for comparing populations that differ greatly with respect to demographic characteristics. Measurement from the perspective of the elderly minimizes the impact of demographic variation; see Ruggles (1987, 1994, 2003).

6Moreover, some analysts have argued that the net effects of US fertility decline on long-term change in coresidence were negligible (Kramarow 1995; Ruggles 1994, 1996).

7An earlier version of this analysis also incorporated the singulate mean age at first marriage for each sex following the method described by Hajnal (1953, 1965). Marriage age is a key determinant of the timing of fertility and affects the availability of married children and grandchildren for coresidence. Several colleagues, including George Alter and Brian Gratton, have argued that the European pattern of late marriage is an inextricable facet of the Northwest European family system. Therefore, they maintain, controlling for marriage age leads to underestimated predicted coresidence. To address this concern, I excluded marriage age from the analysis. By omitting marriage age, however, the current model does not fully control for the demographic constraints on coresidence posed by late marriage and long generations. Accordingly, I expect that the predicted coresidence for Norway, Sweden, and Britain in Figures 4 through 6 is now somewhat overestimated.

8As noted above, married couples in this analysis are treated as single observations, so these statistics are not directly comparable to the percentage of all elderly persons in each category.

9The models would not be well suited to this purpose in any case. The collection of available data is not a random sample of countries. Moreover, the available observations are not independent of one another; there are usually multiple observations from the same country or the same region, so spatial autocorrelation may occur.

10Taken as a group, the nineteenth-century samples from Northwest Europe and North America had a marginally lower percentage of three-generation families than predicted (p<.05), as measured by adding an indicator variable identifying those censuses to the regression. The same indicator variable had no discernible effect on the models of residence with kin or descendants.

11Age at marriage was exceptionally late in nineteenth-century Norway and Sweden. Among the twentieth-century developing countries included in this analysis, only South Africa had marriage age as late as the nineteenth-century Scandinavian countries. Scotland and Canada also had very late marriage. Nineteenth-century England and the United States had more moderate marriage ages, but marriage still occurred later than the average for developing countries in the second half of the twentieth century. The percentage never marrying was high in nineteenth-century Norway, Sweden, and Scotland. In those countries, between 17.1 and 18.9 percent of women aged 45–54 had never married, and between 10.2 and 12.5 percent of men had never married. In Canada, England and Wales, and the United States in the nineteenth century, however, the percentage never marrying was not unusually high compared with recent developing countries.

12On headship pattern in the United States, see Ruggles (2007). The table below documents headship patterns for intergenerational coresidence in the other nineteenth-century Northwest European and North American countries.

Percent of elderly persons heading their household among persons aged 65+ residing with a child aged 18+

Canada 1901NorwaySweden 1900England and Wales 1881Scotland 1881
18751900
Percent62.958.378.578.572.577.6
N7,99113,55026,64322,36217,67221,839

13Reher (1998) argues that the weak-family system of Northwest Europe was still readily detectable at the end of the twentieth century, and this is inconsistent with a theory that the weak-family system disappeared in the nineteenth century.

  • Anderson Michael. Family Structure in Nineteenth Century Lancashire. Cambridge: Cambridge University press; 1971. [Google Scholar]
  • Berkner Lutz. The stem family and the developmental cycle of the peasant household: An eighteenth century Austrian example. American Historical Review. 1972;77:398–418. [Google Scholar]
  • Berkner Lutz. The use and misuse of census data in the historical study of family structure. Journal of Interdisciplinary History. 1975;5:721–738. [Google Scholar]
  • Bongaarts J. Household size and composition in the developing world in the 1990s. Population Studies. 2001;55:263–279. [Google Scholar]
  • Bongaarts John, Zimmer Zachary. Living arrangements of the elderly in the developing world: An analysis of DHS household surveys. Journal of Gerontology: Social Sciences. 2002;57:S145–S157. [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • Brown J Douglas. The Genesis of Social Security in America. Princeton: Industrial Relations Section, Princeton University; 1969. [Google Scholar]
  • Burch Thomas K. The size and structure of families: A comparative analysis of census data. American Sociological Review. 1967;32:347–363. [Google Scholar]
  • Burgess Ernest W. The Function of Socialization in Social Evolution. Chicago: University of Chicago Press; 1916. [Google Scholar]
  • Burgess Ernest W. Family structure and relationships. In: Burgess Ernest W., editor. Aging in Western Societies. Chicago: University of Chicago Press; 1960. pp. 271–298. [Google Scholar]
  • Cain Mead, McNicoll Geoffrey. Population growth and agrarian outcomes. In: Lee Ronald D, et al., editors. Population, Food and Rural Development. Oxford: Clarendon Press; 1988. pp. 101–117. [Google Scholar]
  • Cattell Maria G. Being comparative: Methodological issues in cross-cultural gerontology. Journal of Cross-Cultural Gerontology. 1989;4:75–81. [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • Chattopadhyay Arpita, Marsh Robert. Changes in living arrangement and familial support for the elderly in Taiwan: 1963–1991. Journal of Comparative Family Studies. 1999;30:523–537. [Google Scholar]
  • Clague Ewan. Social Security Administration Headquarters; Baltimore: 1961. Jul 20 [accessed 18 January 2007]. “Factors contributing to the passage of the Social Security Act,” lecture delivered. Available at « http://www.ssa.gov/history/officials.html». [Google Scholar]
  • Cowgill Donald O. The aging of populations and societies. Annals of the American Academy of Political and Social Science. 1974;415:1–18. [Google Scholar]
  • Cowgill Donald O, Holmes Lowell D. Aging and Modernization. New York: Appleton-Century-Crofts; 1972. [Google Scholar]
  • Demos John. Notes on life in Plymouth Colony. William and Mary Quarterly. 1965;22:264–286. [Google Scholar]
  • De Vos Susan, Lee Yean-Ju. Change in extended family living among elderly people in South Korea, 1970–1980. Economic Development and Cultural Change. 1993;41:377–393. [Google Scholar]
  • Durkheim Émile. Introduction à la sociologie de la famille. Annales de la faculté du lettres du Bordeaux. 1888;10:257–282. [Google Scholar]
    Traugott Mark., translator. Émile Durkheim on Institutional Analysis. Chicago: University of Chicago Press; pp. 205–228. [Google Scholar]
  • Eliot Thomas A. Social Security Administration Headquarters; Baltimore: 1961. Feb 3 [accessed 18 January 2007]. “The legal background of the Social Security Act,” Speech delivered. Available at « http://www.ssa.gov/history/officials.html». [Google Scholar]
  • Elman Cheryl, Uhlenberg Peter. Co-residence in the early twentieth century: Elderly women in the United States and their children. Population Studies. 1995;49:501–517. [Google Scholar]
  • Goode William J. World Revolution and Family Patterns. Glencoe: Free Press; 1963. [Google Scholar]
  • Goody Jack. Comparing family systems in Europe and Asia: Are there different sets of rules? Population and Development Review. 1996;22:1–20. [Google Scholar]
  • Greven Philip J., Jr Family structure in seventeenth-century Andover, Massachusetts. William and Mary Quarterly. 1966;23:234–256. [Google Scholar]
  • Haber Carole, Gratton Brian. Old Age and the Search for Security: An American Social History. Bloomington: Indiana University Press; 1994. [Google Scholar]
  • Hajnal John. Age at marriage and proportions marrying. Population Studies. 1953;7:111–136. [Google Scholar]
  • Hajnal John. European marriage patterns in perspective. In: Glass DV, Eversley DEC, editors. Population in History. Chicago: Aldine; 1965. pp. 101–138. [Google Scholar]
  • Hajnal John. Two kinds of preindustrial household formation system. Population and Development Review. 1982;8:449–494. [Google Scholar]
  • Hammel EA. The elderly in the bosom of the family: La famille souche and hardship reincorporation. In: Kertzer David I, Laslett Peter., editors. Aging in the Past: Demography, Society and Old Age. Berkeley: University of California Press; 1995. pp. 107–127. [Google Scholar]
  • Hareven Tamara K. Aging and generational relations: A historical and life course perspective. Annual Review of Sociology. 1994;20:437–461. [Google Scholar]
  • Hareven Tamara K. Introduction: Aging and generational relations over the life course. In: Hareven Tamara K., editor. Aging and Generational Relations over the Life Course: A Historical and Cross-Cultural Perspective. Berlin: de Gruyter; 1996. pp. 1–12. [Google Scholar]
  • Hartman Maryº S. The Household and the Making of History: A Subversive View of the Western Past. New York: Cambridge University Press; 2004. Helvering v Davis, 301 U.S. 619 1937. [Google Scholar]
  • Hermalin Albert I, Ofstedal Mary Beth, Chang Ming-Cheng. Types of supports for the aged and their providers in Taiwan. In: Hareven Tamara K., editor. Aging and Generational Relations: Life-Course and Cross-Cultural Perspectives. New York: Aldine de Gruyter; 1992. pp. 179–215. [Google Scholar]
  • Hirosima K. Projection of living arrangements of the elderly in Japan: 1990–2010. Genus. 1997;53:79–111. [Google Scholar]
  • Holmes Ellen R, Holmes Lowell D. Other Cultures, Elder Years. Thousand Oaks: Sage; 1995. [Google Scholar]
  • Kertzer David I. Toward a historical demography of aging. In: Kertzer David I, Laslett Peter., editors. Aging in the Past: Demography, Society and Old Age. Berkeley: University of California Press; 1995. pp. 363–385. [Google Scholar]
  • Knodel John, Debavalya Nibhon. Living arrangements and support among the elderly in South-East Asia: An introduction. Asia-Pacific Population Journal. 1997;12:5–16. [Google Scholar]
  • Knodel John, Friedman Jed, Anh Truong Si, Cuong Bui The. Intergenerational exchanges in Vietnam: Family size, sex composition, and the location of children. Population Studies. 2000;54:89–104. [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • Knodel John, Ofstedal Mary Beth. Patterns and determinants of living arrangements. In: Hermalin Albert I., editor. The Well-Being of the Elderly in Asia: A Four-Country Comparative Study. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press; 2002. pp. 143–184. [Google Scholar]
  • Kobrin Frances E. The fall in household size and the rise of the primary individual in the United States. Demography. 1976;13:127–138. [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • Kramarow Ellen A. The elderly who live alone in the United States: Historical perspectives on household change. Demography. 1995;32:335–352. [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • Lamanna Mary Ann. Emile Durkheim on the Family. Thousand Oaks: Sage; 2002. [Google Scholar]
  • Laslett Peter. The World We Have Lost. London: Methuen; 1965. [Google Scholar]
  • Laslett Peter. Introduction: The history of the family. In: Laslett Peter, Wall Richard., editors. Household and Family in Past Time. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press; 1972. pp. 1–89. [Google Scholar]
  • Laslett Peter. Family and household as work group and kin group: Areas of traditional Europe compared. In: Wall R, Robin J, editors. Family Forms in Historic Europe. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press; 1983. pp. 513–563. [Google Scholar]
  • Laslett Peter, Harrison John. Historical Essays 1600–1730: Presented to Davis Ogg. London: 1963. Clayworth and Cogenhoe. [Google Scholar]
  • Le Play Frédéric. L’organisation de la famille selon le vrai modèle signalé par l’histoire de toutes les races et de tous les temps. 3. Tours: A. Mame; 1884. [Google Scholar]
  • Levy Marion. Aspects of the analysis of family structure. In: Coale Ansley J, Fallers Lloyd J, Levy Marion J, Jr, Schneider David M, Tomkins Silvan S., editors. Aspects of the Analysis of Family Structure. Princeton: Princeton University Press; 1965. pp. 1–63. [Google Scholar]
  • Logan John R, Bian Fuqin. Family values and coresidence with married children in China. Social Forces. 1998;77:1253–1282. [Google Scholar]
  • Macfarlane Alan. The Origins of English Individualism: The Family, Property and Social Transition. New York: Cambridge University Press; 1978. [Google Scholar]
  • Macfarlane Alan. Marriage and Love in England: Modes of Reproduction 1300–1840. Oxford: Blackwell; 1986. [Google Scholar]
  • Macfarlane Alan. The Culture of Capitalism. Oxford: Blackwell; 1987. [Google Scholar]
  • Martin Linda G. Changing intergenerational family relations in East Asia. Annals of the American Academy of Political and Social Science. 1990;510:102–114. [Google Scholar]
  • Minnesota Population Center. Integrated Public Use Microdata Series—International: Version 3.0. Minneapolis: University of Minnesota; 2007. [Google Scholar]
  • North Atlantic Population Project. NAPP Version 1.0 [computer files] Minneapolis, MN: Minnesota Population Center [distributor]; 2006. NAPP: Complete Count Microdata. [Google Scholar]
  • Nimkoff Meyer F. Changing family relationships of older people in the United States during the last fifty years. In: Tibbitts Clark, Donahue Wilma., editors. Social and Psychological Aspects of Aging. New York: Columbia University Press; 1962. pp. 405–414. [Google Scholar]
  • Ogburn William E. Recent Social Trends in the United States: Report of the President’s Research Committee on Social Trends. New York: McGraw Hill; 1933. The family and its functions; pp. 661–708. [Google Scholar]
  • Palloni Alberto. Ageing and Living Arrangements of Older Persons: Critical Issues and Policy Responses, Population Bulletin of the United Nations. Special Issue 42/43. New York: United Nations; 2001. Living arrangements of older persons; pp. 54–110. [Google Scholar]
  • Parsons Talcott. The social structure of the family. In: Anshen Ruth N., editor. The Family: Its Function and Destiny. New York: Harper; 1944. pp. 173–201. [Google Scholar]
  • Reher David Sven. Family ties in Western Europe: Persistent contrasts. Population and Development Review. 1998;24:203–234. [Google Scholar]
  • Ruggles Steven. Prolonged Connections: The Rise of the Extended Family in Nineteenth Century England and America. Madison: University of Wisconsin Press; 1987. [Google Scholar]
  • Ruggles Steven. The transformation of American family structure. American Historical Review. 1994;99:103–128. [Google Scholar]
  • Ruggles Steven. Living arrangements of the elderly in America, 1880–1980. In: Hareven Tamara K., editor. Aging and Generational Relations Over the Life Course: A Historical and Cross-Cultural Perspective. Berlin: de Gruyter; 1996. pp. 254–271. [Google Scholar]
  • Ruggles Steven. Multigenerational families in nineteenth-century America. Continuity and Change. 2003;18:139–165. [Google Scholar]
  • Ruggles Steven. The decline of intergenerational coresidence in the United States, 1850 to 2000. American Sociological Review. 2007;72:962–989. [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • Ruggles Steven, Heggeness Misty. Intergenerational coresidence in developing countries. Population and Development Review. 2008;34:253–281. [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
  • Ruggles Steven, Sobek Matthew, Alexander Trent, Fitch Catherine A, Goeken Ronald, Hall Patricia Kelly, King Miriam, Ronnander Chad. Integrated Public Use Microdata Series: Version 3.0 [Machine-readable database] Minneapolis: Minnesota Population Center [producer and distributor]; 2008. [Google Scholar]
  • Siegel Jacob S, Swanson David, Shryock Henry S. The Methods and Materials of Demography: Condensed Edition. Bingley, UK: Emerald Group Publishing; 2004. [Google Scholar]
  • Silver Catherine B., editor. Frédéric Le Play on Family, Work, and Social Change. Chicago: University of Chicago; 1982. [Google Scholar]
  • Smith Daniel Scott. Life course, norms, and the family system of older Americans in 1900. Journal of Family History. 1979;4:285–298. [Google Scholar]
  • Smith Daniel Scott. Accounting for change in the families of the elderly in the United States, 1900– present. In: Van Tassel David, Stearns Peter N., editors. Old Age in a Bureaucratic Society: The Elderly, the Experts, and the State in American History. Westport: Greenwood; 1986. [Google Scholar]
  • Soldo Beth J. The living arrangements of the elderly in the near future. In: Kiesler SB, Morgan JN, Oppenheimer VK, editors. Aging: Social Change. New York: Academic Press; 1981. pp. 491–512. [Google Scholar]
  • Thornton Arland. Reading History Sideways: The Fallacy and Enduring Impact of the Developmental Paradigm on Family Life. Chicago: University of Chicago Press; 2005. [Google Scholar]
  • United Nations. Living Arrangements of Older Persons around the World. New York: United Nations; 2005. [Google Scholar]
  • Wall Richard. Leaving home and living alone: An historical perspective. Population Studies. 1989;43:369–389. [Google Scholar]
  • Wall Richard. Elderly persons and members of their households in England and Wales from preindustrial times to the present. In: Kertzer David I, Laslett Peter., editors. Aging in the Past. Berkeley: University of California Press; 1995. pp. 81–106. [Google Scholar]
  • Wister AV, Burch Thomas K. Fertility and household status of older women in Canada, 1921. Canadian Studies in Population. 1983;10:1–13. [Google Scholar]
  • World Bank. World Development Indicators Online. 2007. [accessed 22 August 2007]. Available at « http://devdata.worldbank.org/dataonline/».